LIFE IN THE END ZONE: A discussion of topical issues for anyone concerned with the final phase of life by Muriel R. Gillick, MD
September 30, 2014
To Cover or Not to Cover
A chest CT scan showing what is almost certainly lung cancer: the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services will decide soon whether to cover screening for lung cancer with CT scans. The debate heats up as the decision nears. My thoughts coming next weekend.
September 28, 2014
The Coming Cataclysm
Some time in the next 6 years the world will experience an
unprecedented cataclysm. Not a tsunami or an epidemic or a large scale
war, although those are possible, too. This seismic shift will go undetected by
the majority of the world’s population and yet it will change our lives.
Between 2015 and 2020, for the first time in world history, the population of
people over 65 will be greater than the population of children under 4.
It’s all nicely laid out in a report issued a few months ago
that didn’t get very much attention. I didn’t notice it at all. It was the US Census Bureau’s Report “65+ in the United States” and it consists of nothing
but statistics. Most of the observations and the predictions are nothing
new: the population of older people has grown (it reached 40.3 million in
2010); the median age is increasing (up from 22.9 in 1900 to 37.2 in 2010);
life expectancy has shot up (going from 47.3 at birth in 1900 to 78.7 at birth
in 2010 and going from 11.9 years at age 65 in 1900 to 19.2 years in 2010);
more women than men make it to old age (in the over 90 set, there are only 38
men for every 100 women); the population is becoming more diverse: 84.8% of the
population self-identify as white in 2010 compared to 86.9% in 2000).
But buried amid the welter of interesting but not novel data
about the US are some striking statistics about the entire world. First and
foremost is the unprecedented demographic shift that will take place between 2015 and 2020:
the total number of people over age 65 will exceed the number who are 4 or
younger. This is because both fertility and mortality rates have been falling. As a result, people over 60 went from 8% to 11% of the population between 1950 and 2011, but by 2050 they will make up 22% of the world's population--2 billion people. Looked at a little differently, the global population is projected to increase by a factor of 3.7 between 1950 and 2050, but during that same century, people who are 60+ will go up by a factor of 10 and people who are 80+ by a factor of 26.
Today, the countries with the highest proportion of people over 60 are Japan (31%), Italy (27%), and Germany (26%) with 7 other European countries not far behind. But the countries that are aging most rapidly include 4 in the Middle East (UAE, Iran, and Oman) and 4 in Asia (Singapore, Korea, Viet Nam, and China).
Accompanying the shifting age distribution will be an ever more dramatic dependency ratio: the number of people over 65 for every 100 people aged 20-64. This means that fewer and fewer young people will have to sustain more and more old people. And it will be in the low and middle income countries that all this transformation will be occurring most rapidly.
Today, the countries with the highest proportion of people over 60 are Japan (31%), Italy (27%), and Germany (26%) with 7 other European countries not far behind. But the countries that are aging most rapidly include 4 in the Middle East (UAE, Iran, and Oman) and 4 in Asia (Singapore, Korea, Viet Nam, and China).
Accompanying the shifting age distribution will be an ever more dramatic dependency ratio: the number of people over 65 for every 100 people aged 20-64. This means that fewer and fewer young people will have to sustain more and more old people. And it will be in the low and middle income countries that all this transformation will be occurring most rapidly.
The reason all this matters is that it will put an enormous
strain—economic, medical, and social—on everyone, but especially on the poorest
countries in the world. It will affect demand—for goods (more walkers than
tricycles) and for labor (more personal care attendants than elementary school
teachers). The net effect may be as destabilizing as nuclear weapons. As a
position paper published by the State Department and the National Institute on
Aging put it, global aging represents a “triumph of medical, social, and
economic advances over disease”—but it also represents an enormous and most
governments have not even begun to plan for the long term.
So we have one more thing to worry about, along with climate
change and religious fundamentalism and infectious diseases. What can we do
about it? We do not need to accept the doomsday scenario of massive workforce
shortages, asset market meltdowns, economic growth slowdowns, financial
collapse of pension and healthcare systems, and mass loneliness and insecurity.
But we do need to take steps now.
There are lots of interventions that can make a difference.
One is to raise the normal legal retirement age. Another is
to use international migration. A third is to reform health care systems,
incorporating new models of long term care. A fourth is to encourage businesses
to employ older workers, enabling them to work part time and facilitating their
continuing productivity through environmental modifications that address
mobility, vision, hearing, and other deficits. Economists, sociologists,
demographers, historians and physicians at places including the World Bank and
the Stanford University Center on Longevity have come up with a menu of
strategies.
September 24, 2014
September 21, 2014
From Dust to Dust (or Dustbin?)
The new IOM report,
“Dying in America,” is a masterpiece. Written in the
matter-of-fact language typical of non-partisan reports by committees of experts,
it makes recommendations with which no rational person could possibly disagree.
Of course a few extremists have already gone on record as disagreeing: a
spokesman for the National Right-to-Life movement was quoted in the NY Times as
claiming that the report’s alleged focus on “cost slashing” would reinforce
“well-founded fears” that advance care planning is intended to “push patients
to accept premature deaths.” The truth is that the report says relatively little about cost and what it does
say is simply that a side effect of following its recommendations, suggestions
made in the spirit of improving the quality of care and assuring that patients’
wishes are followed, will likely be a fall rather than a rise in the cost of
health care.
The report includes
“clinician-patient communication and advance care planning” as the topic of one
of its 5 recommendations, and it is presumably this section that is the core of
the right wing critique. But the explicit goal of advance care planning is to enable patients to participate in decisions about their health care and to make
those decisions in accordance with their values, goals, and (informed)
preferences. The report rightly recognizes that this isn’t going to happen
unless clinicians take the initiative and that all the planning in the world will be
inconsequential unless it is implemented when you become ill. The idea that discussing what kind of medical care you want near the end
of life is tantamount to suicide is patently absurd. It would be more accurate
to say that failing to discuss your wishes is tantamount to assuring you will
spend your final days in the hospital, tethered to machines, and in pain.
While the
recommendations of “Dying in America” are straight-forward and unobjectionable,
they are also cleverly designed to be “actionable,” to lead to concrete steps
to promote change. Its recommendation regarding the delivery of care states
that “government health insurers and care delivery programs, as well as private
health insurers, should cover the provision of comprehensive care for
individuals with advanced serious illness who are nearing the end of life.”
This is in marked contrast to the language of the IOM’s 1998 report,
“Approaching Death: Improving Care at the End of Life,” which addressed the
same theme by urging that “people with advanced, potentially fatal illnesses
and those close to them should be able to expect and receive reliable,
skillful, and supportive care.” The only way that patients can “expect” to
receive this kind of care is if the delivery system provides it.
In a similar spirit,
“Dying in America” tackles professional education and development by urging
that certification, licensure, and accreditation of clinicians require evidence
of competency in palliative care. By contrast,
the earlier report exhorted educators and other health professionals to
“initiate changes in undergraduate, graduate, and continuing education to
ensure that practitioners have relevant attitudes, knowledge, and skills to
care well for dying patients.” Without specifying what those changes are or
requiring that they be reflected in licensing exams or accreditation processes,
not very much will—or did—happen.
Finally, the new
report singles out payment systems as critical to promoting change, suggesting
that health care delivery systems—the networks of hospitals, doctors, and
clinics that actually provide medical care—must provide the services that
comprise comprehensive palliative care and health insurers must pay for them. The preceding report acknowledged the role of financing, but
embedded its recommendation amongst a series of quality improvement measures
and spoke in very general terms of the need to “revise mechanisms for financing
care so that they encourage rather than impede good end-of-life care.”
The weakest
recommendations of both old and new reports on dying are for ongoing public
education and engagement. Other than the specific suggestion that professional societies should publish brochures and that
government agencies should support relevant research, there is little
beyond a vague exhortation that faith-based organizations, consumer groups and
others talk about the end of life. Previous public engagement campaigns, of
which the Robert Wood Johnson’s multi-million dollar “Last Acts” program was
the most spectacular and the “Conversation Project” the most recent, proved
disappointing. Perhaps the forthcoming campaign, to be supported by the same
anonymous donor who subsidized (but had no control over the contents of) the
current report, will elaborate further.
My main concern is
that this spectacular report will be filed away, as happens with so many
comprehensive, thoughtful reports on all sorts of topics Certainly the IOM has
had some notable successes. “To Err is Human: Building a Safer Health System,” issued in 1999, did shine a bright light on medical errors and catalyzed efforts to make American
hospitals safer. But the IOM has produced 898 reports, according to its
website. How many of those have had an impact and how much impact have they
had?
I could just as well
ask: What makes a book a best seller? Why do certain fashions catch on and not
others? Publicists have their own ideas about how to sell books (which, speaking from experience, tend to be pretty unimaginative and outdated); Madison Avenue
has its model for advertising campaigns and marketing strategies. Malcolm
Gladwell, in his book “The Tipping Point,”itself a bestseller,
argued that to create a “social epidemic,” you need 3 crucial kinds of people
(connectors, mavens, and salesmen), you need to make sure the content is
“sticky enough” to be retained by those who are affected, and you need to be
sure the context is right.
“Dying in America” lays out the facts and the
arguments. It offers "actionable" recommendations, but the question is whether anyone will act on them. The implementation campaign must begin now, otherwise this magnificent report on
“dust to dust” will go into the dustbin.
September 16, 2014
September 14, 2014
The Methuselah Prize
A startling
new project was unveiled last Tuesday in the San Francisco Bay area. No, not
Apple’s iPhone 6 or its watch, but the Palo Alto Longevity Prize. Never heard
of it? Well, you still have a few more months to sign up to enter the
competition to win $1 million for unlocking the secret to immortality. Is this
just hype or is there some hope here for an important scientific breakthrough?
The basic
idea is this: what we are doing now, attacking the maladies of old age one at a time, is simply trading off one bad disease for another. We’re already succeeding: the death rate from cardiovascular disease has fallen over the
past several decades—and the death rate from Alzheimer’s disease has risen. As
long as human life expectancy remains stable, we’re talking about a zero sum
game in which you fix one problem and substitute another. So far, it looks as
though dementia will be the big winner, which makes research aimed at turning
off the switch that triggers all the diseases of old age very appealing. The underlying
assumption of longevity research is that the degenerative diseases such as cancer, heart failure, and dementia are the result of the aging process. Preventing
all the conditions that both limit life’s duration and impair its quality seems
far more attractive than the disease-specific approach. But is it feasible and
is it ethical?
The majority
of credible scientists believe that life-extension is a very hard problem whose
solution is not around the corner. The Palo Alto Longevity Prize, to the credit
of its mastermind at Palo Alto Investors, Yoon Jun, is focused on somewhat more
modest and potentially achievable goals. Part one of the prize is $500,000, to
be awarded in June, 2016. It will go to a team that can restore the
adaptive capacity of a laboratory animal; specifically, an aging animal will
need to regain the heart rate variability characteristic of its youth. Part two
of the prize is another $500,000 award, to be granted a year later to a team
that increases an animal’s longevity by 50%. In both cases, the scientists will
have to achieve their goal by enabling the animal to preserve homeostasis—the
ability to maintain the status quo (temperature, blood pressure, etc) in the
face of a stimulus, a capacity that is gradually lost with aging. Is this a
worthwhile goal?
Impaired
capacity for homeostasis is at the heart of frailty. The reason people lose their balance and fall easily, or get pneumonia when they contract the flu, or
become confused when they are hospitalized is that they are vulnerable to
modest “stresses.” So the key to physical frailty, and quite possibly to
cognitive frailty (dementia) as well, is maintaining homeostasis. The Longevity
Prize seeks to figure out how to do just that, but it is not without risks. As the
Struldbrugs of Gulliver’s Travels showed, immortality without eternal youth is
tantamount to hell-on-earth: failing vision, declining hearing, impaired
cognition with no escape through death. Suppose unlocking the key to
immortality does indeed prevent cancer and heart disease—but not arthritis and
visual loss? The idea is to prevent all the degenerative conditions of old age,
but suppose there isn’t just one switch, but several?
Even if we
had confidence that achieving a longer life would not create a race of
Struldbrugs, is it a good idea to devote scarce resources to trying to find the
key to immortality? As NIH funding shrinks and the need to prioritize research
questions grows, surely there are more urgent medical questions than how to
live longer. Most people would opt to prevent premature death (infant
mortality, teen suicide, cancer deaths in middle age) before they seek
life-extension past the biblical allotment of three score and ten. Most
physicians who witness the numerous ways patients suffer throughout life’s
trajectory would recommend focusing on quality of life before quantity. And
many people worry that if researchers did come up with an elixir of life, it
would be so expensive that only a very small number of people could afford it,
creating a new elite of Immortals. So
perhaps government should not fund longevity research, but what about the private
sector? Google invested in Calico, a biotech startup devoted to finding ways to
reverse aging. Earlier
this month, Calico opened a new research facility in San Francisco where many
talented scientists will search for the elusive spigot that can turn off the
aging process. People in a free society choose to do all kinds of surprising
things: they go bungee jumping, they sign up to travel to Mars, they smoke
cigarettes. If Google wants to invest some of its advertising revenue on
preventing the degenerative conditions associated with aging, why not?
If it’s
reasonable to work on longevity, is offering a prize the right way to go? This
approach got quite a bit of media attention a few years ago when Netflix
promised $1 million to an individual or team that could improve its predictions
of the movie ratings of individual viewers by 10%. This challenge stimulated a
great many computer science graduate students and faculty members to spend hours trying to solve the problem. I know because my oldest son was
one of them and he wrote about the math underlying the Netflix challenge for
the on-line science journal, Science 2.0 when, after 3 years, a winner was
announced. It turned
out to be a good strategy for Netflix: for a relatively modest investment, the
company recruited many fine minds to work on what would prove to be a difficult
problem, without having to pay benefits or to pin their hopes for a solution
entirely on one individual. Other organizations have issued similar challenges:
the Millennium Prize, for example, announced by the Clay Mathematics Institute
in 2000, offers $1 million for the solution to each of 7 great unsolved
mathematics problems. As of today, only one of the 7 has been solved (and the
individual to whom it was awarded, the reclusive and quirky Russian
mathematician Grigori Perelman, declined the prize).
Perhaps the
earliest use of a financial incentive to solve a scientific problem was the
“Longitude Prize,” offered by the British Parliament in 1714 for an answer to
how sailors could correctly establish their position at sea. Sailors had long
used the stars to determine their latitude, but until the clockmaker John Hunter
got his 20,000 pounds (worth about $5 million today) for solving the longitude
challenge in 1765, they had been unable to determine their longitude. In
recognition of the success of the first Longitude Prize—it was probably the last
great breakthrough in navigation before Global Positioning Systems—a public
private partnership in England recently launched the Longitude Prize 2014. This
competition took an old approach and added a new wrinkle. A panel of experts
came up with a list of 6 scientific problems in desperate need of a solution,
and then asked the British public to vote on which one to sponsor. The election
was held in June and the winner was the problem of antibiotic resistance:
designing an easy to use, cost-effective way to test for antibiotic sensitivity
at the point of care (which in turn would prevent doctors from giving a drug to which the relevant germ would not respond, an all too common scenario that both fails to cure the patient and also promotes further antibiotic resistance). The winner will receive 10 million pounds (about $16 million). Whether the competition will achieve its objective remains to be
seen. In many such competitions,
including the Millennium Prize discussed above, nobody ever wins.
In sum, I
doubt very much that the Longevity Prize will result in immortality and I’m
glad that it’s a hedge fund and not the NIH that is sponsoring the competition.
That said, it’s entirely possible that there will be valuable spinoffs from the
kind of research that the prize is fostering, much as 19th century
anti-aging experiments using animal gland extracts led to hormone replacement
therapy and tissue transplantation was stimulated by early 20th century
experiments in rejuvenation through grafting.
September 10, 2014
September 07, 2014
Is Medicare on the Mend?
A buoyantly
optimistic Paul Krugman proclaimed recently that Medicare’s woes are over—after
a long period of seemingly relentlessly rising costs, costs that were rising so
fast that they were clearly the major threat to the federal budget, Medicare
per beneficiary expenditures actually fell last year. Economics guru and NY Times editorialist Krugman argues that the good news cannot simply be attributed to the recession because
Medicare is a government program and therefore recession-proof. Now it’s
dangerous to take issue with a force such as Krugman. But I want to at least raise the possibility that
Medicare expenditures are not immune to the economic downturn because of the
large amount of money that Medicare beneficiaries pay out of pocket for health
care. And if a patient doesn’t get a drug prescription filled, for example,
because his co-pay is too high, then Medicare does not have to pay for that drug, and expenditures fall. In this vein, a report released in July by the Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation, “How much
is enough? Out-of-pocket spending among Medicare beneficiaries: a chartbook” is
very sobering.
The main findings of
the report (see chart in previous post) are that fee-for-service Medicare recipients spent an average of
$4734 out of pocket for health care in 2010, up from $3253 in 2000--a 44%
increase. Most of that spending is by those age 85 or older: they spent an
average of $5962 out of pocket compared to only $1926 for those ages
65-74. And older people with 3 or more “ADL
deficits,” or difficulties carrying out basic daily activities, spent a mind-boggling $9200 on health care, mainly on services. Out of pocket spending
went to items such as Medicare premiums, other supplementary insurance, and long
term care. In addition, 11% went to paying for prescription
drugs as Medicare Part D has evolved since its inception to include more and
more cost shifting to patients.
Interestingly, my
colleagues at the Harvard Pilgrim Health Care Institute, just
published a study in Health Affairs in which they present data indicating that
older patients are increasingly skipping pills, taking less than the prescribed
doses of medicines, or failing to fill prescriptions altogether in order to
save money: among patients with 4 or more chronic conditions, they found that while 14.9% experienced “cost-related medication nonadherence” in 2005, this rate
fell steadily until it reached 10.2% in 2009, and then it began rising again,
reaching 10.8% in 2011.
So it is entirely
possible that the fall in Medicare costs reflects at least in part decisions made by patients to
forgo particular pricey interventions. The result, predictably, would be
savings to the entire Medicare program. Now whether such choices made by
patients adversely affects their health is another matter. The Health Affairs study assumes that
non-adherence to medications is likely to lead to adverse health outcomes
including worth health states and increased rates of hospitalization,
especially in older individuals with multiple chronic conditions. They base
their assumption on studies from the 1990s, principally conducted in the
mentally ill and in Medicaid patients, that in fact showed that when patients
did not take their medicines as prescribed, their clinical condition
deteriorated. Whether the same would hold true for chronically ill older
patients today is not so clear: there is ample evidence that older individuals with multimorbidity are at increased risk of adverse drug reactions the more
medicines they take and that following the guidelines for all the diseases they
have can cause falling, fainting, confusion, and other problems. Nonetheless, it
would be preferable for physicians to make wiser prescribing decisions based on
an understanding of physiology rather than leaving it to patients to decide
which medications to forgo based on cost.
September 02, 2014
September 01, 2014
Penny Wise, Pound Foolish
What drove me crazy about practicing medicine in a nursing
home wasn’t the patients, although with their many medical problems often
including cognitive impairment they were a challenge; and it wasn’t the
families, though with their anxiety and attentiveness and sometimes their guilt
they were an even greater challenge. What drove me crazy about nursing home
medicine was Medicare billing.
When I saw patients in the nursing home, I was hemmed in by
the fact that Medicare had a very clear idea of what constituted an appointment
with a nursing home patient. According to Medicare, a “visit” (billing jargon)
entailed a face to face “encounter” (more billing jargon) between a “clinician”
(in this case, me, the physician) and the patient.
Once the patient and I were in the same room, I had a script
to follow. I was first supposed to take a “history,” (medicalese for eliciting
symptoms); then I was supposed to do a physical exam, which involved specified
“elements” (examination of particular bodily parts). Finally, I was supposed to
engage in “evaluation and management,” which might result in ordering lab tests
or prescribing a medication. The problem was that in the nursing home
environment, a history and physical, to be useful, looked very different from
what Medicare had in mind. Many of my patients were demented and couldn’t
possibly give a coherent history. Moreover, many of those who had relatively
mild dementia could always be counted on to complain about something, so if it
had been up to the patient, I would have made a visit every day. Many of the
patients had medical conditions that required observation over a prolonged
period, not just at one point in time. For example, a patient with dementia
might have paranoid delusions that significantly affected his or her quality of
life, but those delusions would come and go. A patient with Parkinson’s disease
might have difficulty walking that fluctuated over the course of the day,
depending both on random changes and on when the patient last took medication. As
a result, the most meaningful history and the most useful physical observations
had to be obtained secondhand—from nurses, nurses aides, and other staff
members including physical therapists and social workers. I spent much of my
time interviewing personnel about my patients, time that Medicare did not
recognize as valuable because it was not part of an “encounter.”
Starting in January, 2015, Medicare will pay a special
monthly “complex chronic management” fee on top of the usual reimbursement to
primary care patients who care for patients in
the office. But somehow the nursing home environment is assumed to be
immune from the need for this kind of supplementary support. Calls to family
members and discussions with other members of the interdisciplinary team are
supposed to be part of the “evaluation and management” services that are
“bundled” into the Medicare fee schedule. So it’s thought to be perfectly
reasonable for a physician to be paid $92 in 2015 for a nursing home visit for an acute
medical problem such as a new pneumonia (code 99309). To merit this payment, the physician must provide
documentation that he or she has taken 2 out of 3 possible steps: obtained a
detailed history, performed a detailed physical exam, or engaged in “moderately
complex” medical decision making. Only if the physician takes a comprehensive history,
performs a comprehensive exam, and engages in highly complex medical
decision-making can he or she bill with the code“99310,” earning the somewhat more generous sum of $136.
For comparison, note that a gastroenterologist is paid on average $220 for
performing a colonoscopy, a 20-minute procedure.
No wonder physicians often respond to a call from the
nursing home about a sick patient with an order to send the patient to the
hospital for evaluation. Send a frail nursing home patient to the emergency room and he
has, I would guess, about a 90% chance of being admitted. So instead of paying
a physician an appropriate amount for making a visit to the nursing home and
instituting on-site medical care, Medicare would fork out a minimum of $5774
(the base DRG payment) for a 5-day hospitalization, exposing the patient to the
risk of iatrogenesis. Does this make any sense?
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)